In No Rising Tide Joerg Rieger challenges the relevance of President John F. Kennedy’s well-known
statement that “A rising tide lifts all boats.” (1) As the Occupy movements have brought to the
headlines in recent months, “the gaps between the very wealthy and the rest of
the population keep increasing” and “life-and-death struggles are no longer
just a matter for the poorest of the poor.” (3) Even New York Times columnist Thomas
Friedman, who Rieger identifies as “a long-time supporter of globalization who
[has] great faith in the free market” has said, “We are going to have to learn
to live with a lot more uncertainty for a lot longer than our generation has
ever experiences.” (2)
Rieger challenges us to evaluate our assumptions about the
economy and free markets. Observing that
often we believe “the authority of economics is unquestionable and often even
infallible, and in the assumption that the current system is the only one that
is viable” he suggests that there are parallels between economics and
religion. He cites theologian and Union Theological
Seminary professor Paul Knitter
as one who has gone as far as to say that the market is a religion and therefore,
should be in conversation with other religions. (6)
What would that discourse look like? What would the questions
be? Rieger suggests several: “On which authorities, powers, and energies do we
rely? [Are they the right ones?] What is it that gives us ultimate hope, shapes
our desires, and provides reasonable levels of stability?” (4)
These questions
matter because in this disparate world where we live “power and influence
determine who gets to shape the world, who gets recognized, and whose ideas
count.”(3) One example of an explicit theology
of economics is pronounced by Michael Novak, an American
Enterprise Institute scholar to whom Rieger attributes the idea that “the
status quo should not be challenged since this is the way God intends things to
be.”(6) Arguing that often the
relationship between economics and theology is more implicit than explicit, Rieger
suggests “the principles of mainline economics are mostly taken for granted by
religious communities, presupposed as part of the way things are, and virtually
never discussed in critical fashion.” (10) Because the principles are embedded,
“Hope, even in the midst of the most severe economic crisis, is thus built on
the faith that things will eventually get between and that the reign of
free-market economics will be reaffirmed.” (7)
Why don’t we talk more about “the alternative approaches to
the world of economics”? (11) How can we awaken critical self-reflection of our
economic positions, and initiate a movement away from market fundamentalism
which promotes adherence without “consideration of changes in context or the real
needs and concerns of people?” (14-15) At this point, I am not advocating one
position over another; instead what I want to do is to echo Rieger that we have
a responsibility to understand more about the world in which we live and the
assumptions that are built into the systems and institutions that we live
within.
No comments:
Post a Comment